1. Describe a decision a company has made when facing uncertainty. Compute the expected costs and benefits of the decision. Offer advice on how to proceed. Compute the profit consequences of the advice
2. Identify something you buy or sell that could be bought or sold using an auction. How would you run the auction? Do a benefit-cost analysis of the auction relative to how you currently buy or sell.
The assignment is to answer the question provided above in essay form. This is to be in narrative form. Bullet points should not to be used. The paper should be at least 1.5 – 2 pages in length, Times New Roman 12-pt font, double-spaced, 1 inch margins and utilizing at least one outside scholarly or professional source related to organizational behavior. This does not mean blogs or websites. This source should be a published article in a scholarly journal. This source should provide substance and not just be mentioned briefly to fulfill this criteria. The textbook should also be utilized. Do not use quotes. Do not insert excess line spacing. APA formatting and citation should be used.
CHAPTER
18 Auctions
©2018 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on
a password-protected website for classroom use. ©Kamira/Shutterstock Images
â— In oral or English auctions, the highest bidder wins by
outbidding the second- highest bidder. This means that
the second-highest bidders’ value determines the price.
â— A Vickrey or second-price auction is a sealed-bid auction
in which the high bidder wins but pays only the secondhighest bid. These auctions are equivalent to oral
auctions and are well suited for use on the Internet.
â— In a sealed-bid ï¬Ârst-price auction, the high bidder wins
and pays his value. Bidders must balance the benefits of
bidding higher (a higher probability of winning) against
the costs of bidding higher (reduced margin if they do
win). Optimal bids are less than bidders’ private values.
©2018 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or
otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use. ©Kamira/Shutterstock Images
2
• continued
â— Bidders can increase their proï¬Ât by agreeing not to bid
against one another. Such collusion or bid rigging is
more likely to occur in open auctions and in small,
frequent auctions. If collusion is suspected,
• do not hold open auctions;
• do not hold small and frequent auctions;
• do not disclose information to biddersâ€â€do not announce
who the winners are, who else may be bidding, or what the
winning bids were.
â— In a common-value auction, bidders bid below their
estimates to avoid the winner’s curse. Oral auctions
return higher prices in common-value auctions because
they release more information than sealed-bid auctions.
©2018 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or
otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use. ©Kamira/Shutterstock Images
3
Bell Telephone
â— In 1885, Bell Telephone Company of Canada
established Northern Electric to manufacture its
telephone equipment.
• By 2000, the company (now Nortel) had a market share of
over $200 Billion
• Decade of bad investments, declared bankruptcy in 2011
â— Nortel approved for sale by bankruptcy court
• The court was unsure of the value of some of the company’s
assets, such as the 6000 patents, and decided to sell these
assets with an auction.
• The bidding started at $900 million but was pushed up to
$4.5 billion after successive rounds of bidding.
©2018 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or
otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use. ©Kamira/Shutterstock Images
4
Introduction: Auctions
â— Auctions are simply another form of competition, like
price competition or bargaining.
â— CarBargains is one company that uses auctions to help
car buyers.
• In these auctions, though, sellers not buyers are competing.
• Local car dealers offer prices to a single consumer in a sealedbid auction.
â— Auctions set a price and identify the high-value buyer or
low-cost seller.
â— Auctions are often used in combination with bargaining,
e.g., first an auction is used to identify the high-value
buyers and then there is a negotiation over the final price.
©2018 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or
otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use. ©Kamira/Shutterstock Images
5
Oral Auctions
â— Definition: In an oral or English auction, bidders submit
increasing bids until only one bidder remains. The item is
awarded to this last remaining bidder.
â— Example: Suppose there are five bidders with values equal to
{$5, $4, $3, $2, $1}.
• The $5 bidder will win the auction, and bids only slightly over $4
to do so.
• The “price†or winning bid is $4, or slightly above.
• The winning bidder is willing to pay $5 but doesn’t have to, so
the losing bidders determine the price in oral auctions.
â— Auctions identify the high-value bidder (“efficiencyâ€Â) and set
a price for an item, with no negotiating necessary. For these
reasons, economists love auctions.
©2018 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or
otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use. ©Kamira/Shutterstock Images
6
Benefits of auctions
â— Example: auction vs. posted-price
• A retail store is unsure whether they should price high ($8) or
low ($5) for a certain item.
• If the store prices high, they sell to only high-value buyers (half
the time). If the store prices low, they sell to all customers at a
lower price.
• If MC = $3, then pricing high is preferable
(.5)($8-$3) = $2.50
[versus (1.0)($5-$3) = $2.00]
â— If the store uses an auction instead, and two bidders show
up with values $8 and $5 – meaning there is again a .5
chance of selling to a high-value costumer – what will
the revenue of the sale be?
©2018 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or
otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use. ©Kamira/Shutterstock Images
7
Oral Auctions (cont’d)
Bidder 1
$5
$5
$5
$8
$5
$8
$8
$8
Bidder 1
$5
$5
$8
$8
Bidder 2
$5
$8
$5
$8
Bidder 2
$5
$5
$8
$5
$8
$5
$8
$8
Probability
.25
.25
.25
.25
Winning bid
$5
$5
$5
$8
Bidder 3
$5
$8
$5
$5
$8
$8
$5
$8
Probability
.125
.125
.125
.125
.125
.125
.125
.125
Winning bid
$5
$5
$5
$5
$8
$8
$8
$8
©2018 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or
otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use. ©Kamira/Shutterstock Images
8
Second-Price Auctions
â— Definition: A Vickrey or second-price auction is a
sealed-bid auction in which the item is awarded to
the highest bidder, but the winner pays only the
second-highest bid.
• This at first seems counterintuitive – why leave money
on the table? But second-price auctions encourage
bidders to bid more aggressively.
• William Vickrey and James A. Mirrlees shared the
1996 Nobel Prize in Economics for their work
inventing the Vickrey auction and establishing that
there is no difference in outcome between an oral and
second-price auction.
©2018 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or
otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use. ©Kamira/Shutterstock Images
9
Second-price auctions (cont’d)
â— Because the winning bidder pays the price of the secondhighest bid, bidders are willing to bid up to their values,
so the outcome is the same as an oral auction.
â— Second-price auctions are easier to run than oral auctions
because the bidders can bid in remotely, and
asychronously (at different places and times).
â— Discussion: Why are eBay auctions equivalent to
second-price auctions?
â— Discussion: Why does eBay use second-price auctions?
©2018 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or
otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use. ©Kamira/Shutterstock Images
10
Sealed-Bid Auctions
â— Definition: In a sealed-bid first-price auction, the highest
bidder gets the item at a price equal to the highest bid.
â— These auctions present a difficult trade-off for bidders:
• A higher bid reduces the profit if you win, but
• Also raises probability of winning
â— Bidders balance these two effects by bidding below their
values (“shadingâ€Â).
â— Experience and knowing the competing bidders are the
keys to these auctions, but in general, bid more
aggressively – shade less – if the competition is strong.
©2018 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or
otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use. ©Kamira/Shutterstock Images
11
Bid Rigging or Collusion
â— Example: an oral auction with bidder values of {$5, $4,
$3, $2, $1}.
• Suppose that in this auction the two high-value bidders have
formed a bidding ring (also known as a cartel).
• The two decide NOT to bid against each other, so the cartel wins
the item by outbidding the non-cartel members, i.e., price= $3.
The cartel makes a profit of $1 which typically is split evenly
between members.
â— Bid-rigging is a criminal violation of antitrust laws in the
US and many other countries.
â— In one type of bid-rigging, cartel members re-auction the
items won in a second-auction to cartel members in a
second or “knockout†auction.
©2018 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or
otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use. ©Kamira/Shutterstock Images
12
Bid-rigging / Collusion (cont’d)
â— Another type of collusion is known as a bid-rotation
scheme. This scheme uses quid pro quo bidding
behavior.
â— Bidders in these cartels submit weak bids or refrain from
bidding against each other until it is their turn to “win.â€Â
â— In a bid-rotation scheme each cartel member must wait
for his turn to win – a weakness that leaves these
schemes vulnerable to cheating.
â— Proposition: Collusion is more likely in oral auctions.
â— Proposition: Collusion is more likely in small, frequent
auctions.
©2018 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or
otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use. ©Kamira/Shutterstock Images
13
Bid-rigging: Frozen Fish Conspiracy
â— After this cartel was broken the price of fish dropped 23%
â— Investigators backcast from the competition period into the
collusive period to determine the cartel’s effect, i.e., what the
price would have been, “but for†the conspiracy.
©2018 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or
otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use. ©Kamira/Shutterstock Images
14
Reacting to bid-rigging
â— The government is frequently the victim of bid-rigging
schemes.
◠Learning from the government’s experience, some tips to
avoid collusion:
• Do not rely on purchasing agents (those running the auction)
who have little interest in buying at a low price. Instead, reward
agents for making good (high-quality and low-price) purchases.
• Do not entangle purchasing agents with masses of red tape.
Instead, permit them to negotiate (e.g., to bargain with the
bidders) if they suspect bid rigging.
• But beware of patronage
• Do not use the procurement process to further a social agenda
(small business set-asides, public lands, national defense, etc.)
that is irrelevant to the goal of purchasing goods at low prices.
©2018 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or
otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use. ©Kamira/Shutterstock Images
15
Avoiding collusion (cont’d)
â— Keep cartels in the dark, so it is difficult for them to
organize and to punish cheaters.
• do not hold open auctions;
• do not hold small and frequent auctions;
• do not disclose information to biddersâ€â€do not
announce who the other bidders are, who the winners
are, or what the winning bids are.
©2018 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or
otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use. ©Kamira/Shutterstock Images
16
Common-Value Auctions
â— Definition: In a common-value auction, the value is the same
for each bidder, but no one knows what it is. Each bidder has
only an estimate of the value.
◠Be careful in these auctions lest you suffer the “winner’s
curseâ€Â
• If you win, you learn that you were the one who had the highest
and most optimistic estimate of the unknown value of the item
• Bidders should reduce their value estimates to protect against this.
• If you are the auctioneer, release info to mitigate winners’ curse.
◠Winner’s curse is worse when
• More bidders
• Other bidders have better information
©2018 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or
otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use. ©Kamira/Shutterstock Images
17
Common-Value Auctions (cont’d)
◠To avoid the winner’s curse bid less aggressively as
the number of bidders increases.
â— In common-value settings, oral auctions return
higher prices than sealed-bid auctions because oral
bids reveal information.
• But oral auctions are more vulnerable to collusion.
â— Discussion: Why do bidders wait until the last
minute of the auction to submit bids on eBay?
©2018 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or
otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use. ©Kamira/Shutterstock Images
18
CHAPTER
17 Making Decisions
with Uncertainty
©2018 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on
a password-protected website for classroom use. ©Kamira/Shutterstock Images
â— When you’re uncertain about the costs or beneï¬Âts of
a decision, replace numbers with random variables
and compute expected costs and benefits.
â— Uncertainty in pricing: When customers have
unknown values, you face a familiar trade-off: Price
high and sell only to high-value customers, or price
low and sell to all customers.
â— If you can identify high-value and low-value
customers, you can price discriminate and avoid the
trade-off. To avoid being discriminated against, highvalue customers will try to mimic the behavior and
appearance of low-value customers.
©2018 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or
otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use. ©Kamira/Shutterstock Images
2
• continued
â— Difference-in-difference estimators are a good way
to gather information about the beneï¬Âts and costs of
a decision. The ï¬Ârst difference is before versus after
the decision or event. The second difference is the
difference between a control and an experimental
group.
â— If you are facing a decision in which one of your
alternatives would work well in one state of the
world, and you are uncertain about which state of the
world you are in, think about how to minimize
expected error costs.
©2018 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or
otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use. ©Kamira/Shutterstock Images
3
TeleSwitch
â— A large telecom supplier, TeleSwitch, sold its product
only through distributors.
â— In 2000, their largest clients wanted to deal directly with
TeleSwitch – and avoid the middle man distributor.
TeleSwitch was unsure what to do.
• They might lose large customers if they didn’t switch.
• But, they might lose distributors (and their small
customers) if they did.
• There is a lower probability of losing dealers (because they
would have to incur costs to change suppliers)
• But this would have a much larger impact on profit.
â— How should we analyze decisions like this??
©2018 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or
otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use. ©Kamira/Shutterstock Images
4
Introduction: Undertainty
â— This problem illustrates the type of uncertainty that
exist in most business decisions.
â— This chapter looks at ways to help deal with
uncertainty and arrive at decisions that will best
profit your firm.
â— By modeling uncertainty, you can:
• Learn to make better decisions
• Identify the source(s) of risk in a decisions
• Compute the value of collecting more information.
©2018 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or
otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use. ©Kamira/Shutterstock Images
5
Modeling Uncertainty
â— To model uncertainty we use random variables to
compute the expected costs and benefits of a decision.
â— Definition: a random variable is simply a way of
representing numerical outcomes that occur with
different probabilities.
â— To represent values that are uncertain,
• list the possible values the variable could take,
• assign a probability to each value, and
• compute the expected values (average outcomes) by
calculating a weighted average using the probabilities
as the weights.
©2018 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or
otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use. ©Kamira/Shutterstock Images
6
Random variables
â— Definition: a binomial random variable, X, can
have two values, x1 or x2, with probabilities, p and 1p. The expected value (mean) for a binomial random
variable is:
E[X]=p*x1+(1-p)x2
â— Definition: a trinomial random variable, X, can
have three values, x1, x2, or x3, with probabilities p1,
p2, and 1-p1–p2. The mean for a trinomial random
variable is:
E[X]= p1*x1+ p2*x2+(1- p1-p2) x3
©2018 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or
otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use. ©Kamira/Shutterstock Images
7
How to model uncertainty
◠“Wheel of Cash†example:
• The carnival game wheel is divided like a pie into thirds, with
values of $100, $75, and $5 painted on each of the slices
• The cost to play is $50.00
• Should you play the game?
• Three possible outcomes: $100, $75, and $5 with equal
probability of occurring (assuming the wheel is “fairâ€Â)
• Expected value of playing the game is
1/3 ($100) + 1/3 ($75) + 1/3 ($5) = $60
• But, if the wheel is biased toward the $5 outcome, the
expected value is
1/6 ($100) + 1/6 ($75) + 2/3 ($5) = $32.50
©2018 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or
otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use. ©Kamira/Shutterstock Images
8
TeleSwitch’s Decision Tree
â— The probability of losing customers is 0.6
â— The probability of losing distributors is 0.2
Telecom Firm
Sell directly to large customers
Sell only through dealers
(.20) × $30 + (.80) × $130 = $110
(.60) × $100 + (.40) × $130 = $112
Distributors leave
Distributors stay
Large customers leave
Large customers stay
(probability = .20)
Firm profit = $30
(probability = .80)
Firm profit = $130
(probability = .60)
Firm profit = $100
(probability = .40)
Firm profit = $130
©2018 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or
otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use. ©Kamira/Shutterstock Images
9
Entry Decision with Uncertainty
â— The probability of retaliation (no accommodation) to an entry
decision (as modeled in ch 15) is 0.5
Entrant
Enter
Stay Out
(.50) × $60 + (.50) × $-40 = $10
(.50) × $0 + (.50) × $0 = $0
Incumbent prices high
Incumbent prices low
Incumbent prices high
Incumbent prices low
(probability = .50)
Entrant profit = $60
(probability = .50)
Entrant profit = $-40
(probability = .50)
Entrant profit = $0
(probability = .50)
Entrant profit = $0
©2018 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or
otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use. ©Kamira/Shutterstock Images
10
Dealing with uncertainty
â— Discussion: How do you respond to an invitation from a
friend to invest in a real estate venture that depends on
uncertain future demand and interest rates?
• Calculate the potential gains and loses based on different
combinations of high and low interest rates and high and
low demand
• Whoever proposed the venture probably presented the best
case scenario (low interest rates and high demand) – and
that is the only combination (of four possible outcomes)
under which you will do well.
• Either don’t invest or find a way that aligns your friend’s
incentives with your own, i.e., he gets a payoff only if the
venture does well.
©2018 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or
otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use. ©Kamira/Shutterstock Images
11
Uncertainty in Pricing
â— Uncertainty in pricing arises when the demand for a
product is unknown.
â— To model this uncertainty, classify the number and type
of potential customers. For example:
• High-value consumers willing to pay $8
• Low-value consumers willing to pay $5
• Suppose there are equal numbers of each consumer group
â— Discussion: If MC= $3, what is optimal price?
• By pricing high, you would earn $5 per sale each time a
high-value costumer shops – or %50 of the time
• By pricing low, you would earn $2 per sale but would be
able to sell to both high- and low-value costumers – 100%
of the time.
©2018 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or
otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use. ©Kamira/Shutterstock Images
12
Uncertainty in Pricing (cont’d.)
â— Answer: Price High
Pricing Decision
Price High
Price Low
(.50) × $5 + (.50) × $0 = $2.50
(.50) × $2 + (.50) × $2 = $2
Get high-value customer
Get low-value customer
Get high-value customer
Get low-value customer
(probability = .50)
Profit = $5
(probability = .50)
Profit = $0
(probability = .50)
Profit = $2
(probability = .50)
Profit = $2
©2018 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or
otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use. ©Kamira/Shutterstock Images
13
Price Discrimination Opportunity
â— If you can identify the two types of customers, set
different prices to each group, and prevent arbitrage
between them, then you can price discriminate.
• Price of $8 to the high-value customers
• Price of $5 to the low-value customers.
â— Discussion: When buying a new car, sales people
discriminate between high- and low-value customers.
How do they do this?
â— Discussion: What can you do to defeat this?
©2018 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or
otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use. ©Kamira/Shutterstock Images
14
Natural experiments
â— To gather information about the benefits and costs of
a decision you can run natural experiments.
â— Natural experiment example: A national restaurant
chain
• A regional manager wanted to test the profitability of a
special holiday menu
• To do this, the menu was introduced in half the restaurants
in her region.
• In comparing sales between the new menu locations and
the regular menu locations (the control group) the manager
hoped to isolate the effect of the holiday menu on profit.
©2018 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or
otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use. ©Kamira/Shutterstock Images
15
Natural experiments (cont’d.)
â— This is a difference-in-difference estimator. The first
difference is before vs. after the introduction of the menu; the
second difference is the experimental vs. control groups
â— Difference-in-difference controls for unobserved factors that
can influence changes
â— The manager found that sales jumped during the holiday
season – but the increase was seen both in the control and
experimental groupsâ€â€both increased by the same amount.
◠The manager concluded that the holiday menu’s popularity
came at the expense of the regular menu. So the holiday menu
only cannibalized the regular menu’s demand and didn’t
attract new customers to the restaurant.
©2018 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or
otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use. ©Kamira/Shutterstock Images
16
Natural experiments (cont’d.)
â— Natural experiments can be useful in many different
contexts.
â— When the FTC looked back at a 1998 gasoline
merger in Louisville, they used their own version of
a difference-in-difference estimator.
• Three control cities (Chicago, Houston, and Arlington)
were used to control for demand and supply shocks that
could affect price.
• The first difference was before vs. after the merger; the
second difference was Louisville prices vs. prices in control
cities– this allowed the FTC to isolate the effects of the
merger and determine its effect
©2018 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or
otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use. ©Kamira/Shutterstock Images
17
1998 LouisGasoline Merger
©2018 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or
otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use. ©Kamira/Shutterstock Images
18
Minimizing expected error costs
â— Sometimes, when faced with a decision, instead of
focusing on maximizing expected profits (benefits minus
costs) it can be useful to think about minimizing
expected “error costs.â€Â
â— This approach is helpful when one alternative would
work well only under certain conditions, and you are
uncertain about whether the conditions hold.
• For example, “should we impose a carbon tax?â€Â
• If global warming is caused by human activity then a carbon tax
will help reduce it.
• But if global warming is not caused by human activity, then a
carbon tax would only reduce economic activity and would not
cool the Earth.
©2018 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or
otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use. ©Kamira/Shutterstock Images
19
Error costs (cont’d.)
â— The two global warming alternatives can be modeled by:
Carbon Tax
No Tax
GW is caused by human activity (p) 0
(p) x (error cost II)
GW is not caused by human
activity (1-p)
0
(1-p) x (error cost I)
• Type I error is the failure to tax when global warming (GW) is caused by human activity.
• The Type II error is the implementation of a carbon tax when global warming (GW) is
not caused by human activity.
• The optimal decision is the one with the smaller expected error costs, i.e. Tax if (1p)*Cost(Type I) < p*Cost(Type II)
• This type of analysis is especially useful for balancing the risks associated with pricing
errors (over- v. under-), e.g., for airlines, hotels, cruise ships; as well as production
errors (over v. under)
©2018 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or
otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use. ©Kamira/Shutterstock Images
20
Risk versus uncertainty
â— Risk is how we characterize uncertainty about values that
are variable.
• Risk is modeled using random variables.
â— Uncertainty is uncertainty about the about the
distribution of the random variables.
• E.g., which probabilities should be assigned to the various
values the random variables can take?
â— This difference is critical in financial markets. Risk can be
predicted, priced and traded – people are comfortable with
risk. Dealing with uncertainty is much more difficult.
â— Mistaking risk for uncertainty can be a costly mistake
©2018 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or
otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use. ©Kamira/Shutterstock Images
21
IndyMac: Risk vs. Uncertainty
â— Risk never went away,
investors were just
ignoring it
â— Black Swans & fat tails
I have nothing against
economists: you should let them
entertain each others with their
theories and elegant mathematics,
[But]…do not give any of them
risk-management responsibilities.
â€â€Nassim Nicholas Taleb
©2018 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or
otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use. ©Kamira/Shutterstock Images
22
Dealing with uncertainty
â— Uncertainty is unavoidable. So to cope with uncertainty
in decision making, gather more or better information.
• Best Buy has used dispersed sets of non-experts to predict
future variables, such as a holiday sales rate.
• Google uses internal prediction markets to generate
demand and usage forecasting.
â— The US Marines advise:
• Because we can never eliminate uncertainty, we must learn
to fight effectively despite it. We can do this by developing
simple, flexible plans; planning for likely contingencies;
developing standing operating procedures; and fostering
initiative among subordinates.
©2018 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or
otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use. ©Kamira/Shutterstock Images
23
Risk versus uncertainty
â— Part of the housing crisis can be attributed to an error in translating
uncertainty to risk through a mathematical formula created by
David Li.
• The formula was designed to measure the correlation between returns
of various assets that made up collateralized debt obligations (CDOs).
• But there was uncertainty about how one asset’s failure would related
to that of another asset. There was also a lack of historical data about
relationships among the underlying assets.
◠Li’s solution was to use past credit default swap (CDS) prices as an
indication of correlation returns (clever but imperfect).
• CDS data came from a time when housing prices were on the rise, and
the correlation changed during a period of decreasing prices.
• Nearly everyone was using this formula, and… we’ve seen how it all
turned out
©2018 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or
otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use. ©Kamira/Shutterstock Images
24
CHAPTER
PowerPoint Slides
© Luke M. Froeb,
Vanderbilt 2014
16
Bargaining
â— Strategic view of bargaining: model as either a
simultaneous-move or sequential-move game.
◠A player can gain bigger share of the “pie†by
• changing a simultaneous-move game into a sequentialmove game with a ï¬Ârst-mover advantage;
or by
• committing to a position.
â— Credible commitments (threats) are difficult to make
because they require players to commit to a course of
action against their self-interest. Thus, the best threat
is one you never have to use.
©2018 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or
otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use. ©Kamira/Shutterstock Images
2
• continued
â— The strategic view of bargaining focuses on how the
outcome of bargaining games depends on who moves
ï¬Ârst and who can commit to a bargaining position, as
well as whether the other player can make a counteroffer.
â— The non-strategic view of bargaining focuses on the
gains and alternatives to agreement to determine the
outcome of barganing.
• Main insight: The gains from agreement relative to the
alternatives to agreement determine the terms of any
agreement.
• Anything you can do to increase your opponent’s relative
gains from reaching agreement or to decrease your own
will improve your bargaining position.
©2018 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or
otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use. ©Kamira/Shutterstock Images
3
1: NBA
• In summer 2011, National Basketball Assc. owners were negotiating
with the players’ union over how to split revenues
• Union wanted 57%, owners only offered 50%
• Owners locked out the players, cancelling the start of the season
• After months of legal threats and lost revenue, players finally
accepted owners’ initial offer
4
2: Texaco
• In 1985, Texaco was found guilty by a Texas jury for interfering with
Pennzoil’s attempt to buy Getty Oil.
• Texaco was fined $10.5 billion, but appealed the verdict and began negotiating
with Pennzoil.
• In 1987, Texaco filed for bankruptcy. Pennzoil was then unable to seize
control of Texaco’s assets.
• Texaco was also freed from the responsibility to pay interest and dividends.
• One year later Texaco and Pennzoil settled the case, with Texaco having
to pay only $3 billion. Texaco successfully used bankruptcy to reduce its
liability by over 70%
• This chapter examines bargaining, and strategies to improve your
bargaining position, like those used by Bear Stearns and Texaco .
5
Introduction: Bargaining
• There are two complementary ways to look at bargaining:
• the strategic view analyzes bargaining using the tools of game theory (ch 15).
Bargaining can be viewed as either a simultaneous-move game with two
equilibria or a sequential-move game, where one player gains an advantage by
committing to a position.
• the non-strategic view acknowledges that real life negotiations don’t have fixed
rules as formal games do. This view postulates that the alternatives to
agreement determine the terms of agreement, regardless of the rules of the
negotiating game.
• If you can increase your opponent’s relative gain, or decrease your own, you can gain a
bigger share of the pie.
• By declaring (or threatening) bankruptcy, Bear Stearns and Texaco were able to improve their
bargaining “positionâ€Â, i.e., by changing the alternatives to agreement, they changed the
terms of agreement.
6
Bargaining: a simultaneous-move game
• Example: Wage negotiations
• Management and labor are bargaining over a fixed sum of $200 million
• Two possible strategies are available to each player: “bargain hard†or
“accommodate.â€Â
• If both bargain hard, no deal is reached. Neither side gains.
• If both accommodate, they split the gains from trade.
• If one player bargains hard and the other accommodates, then the player
who bargains hard takes 75% of the “pieâ€Â
7
Bargaining: a simultaneous game (cont.)
• There are two equilibria for this game
• Management prefers the lower-left equilibrium
• Labor prefers the upper-right.
• This bargaining game has the same structure as a game of “chickenâ€Â
• Each party can gain by committing to a position, which turns it into a sequential
game
8
Bargaining: a sequential-move game
• In sequential-move bargaining the first “player†makes an
offer that the second “player†can accept or refuse.
• Again to analyze a sequential-move game look ahead and
reason back.
• The first-mover “looks ahead and reasons back†to determine the
how her rival will react to each possible move. Then the first-mover
can determine the consequences of each possible move.
• In this case, the sequential-move games present a “firstmover advantage,†i.e., by moving first a player can gain an
advantage.
• Using the same wage negotiation example, we can look at
sequential-move bargaining and first-mover advantage.
9
Bargaining game: first-mover advantage
• Management “wins†by moving first and making a low offer
Management
low offer
generous offer
Union
strike
accept
0,0
150 , 50
strike
0,0
accept
50 , 150
10
Bargaining game: first-mover advantage
• Union can change the outcome by credibly committing to strike if a
low offer is made
Management
low offer
generous offer
Union
strike
0,0
strike
0,0
accept
50 , 150
11
Sequential-move bargaining (cont.)
• Because the management has the first-mover
advantage, it is in their best interest to make a low offer,
and it is in the union’s best interest to accept that offer.
• However, if the union can effectively threaten to strike
(in such a way that the management believes them)
they can change the outcome of the game despite
management’s first-mover advantage.
• Credible threats are hard to make because they require the
union act against its self interest.
• If management doesn’t believe the threat, the union might
actually have to follow through on the threat.
• So, again, the best threat is one you never have to use.
12
Non-strategic View of Bargaining
• The outcome in strategic bargaining “games†is dependent
on the rules of the game, but in real life, the rules are not
always clear.
• John Nash proved that any reasonable outcome to a bargain
would maximize the product of the bargainers’ surplus.
• This is known as an “axiomatic†or “non-strategic†view of
bargaining.
• In this view, the gains from bargaining relative to the alternatives
to bargaining, determine the terms of any bargain.
• This view also teaches that to increase your bargaining power,
• you can increase your opponent’s gain from reaching agreement or decrease
your own.
• If your rival has more to gain by agreeing, he becomes more eager to reach
agreement, and accepts a smaller share of the surplus.
13
Non-strategic view (cont.)
• Nash’s axiomatic approach:
•
•
•
•
[ S1(z) – D1 ] x [ (S2(z) – D2 ] , where:
z is the agreement
S1(z) is the value of the agreement to player 1 (sub 2 for player two)
D1 is “disagreement value,†or pay-off if no agreement is reached, for player 1
(sub 2 for player two)
• So player 1’s gain from agreement is (S1(z) – D1)
14
Non-strategic view (cont.)
• For example, two brothers are bargaining over a dollar.
• If no agreement is reached, neither participant gains.
• If they reach an agreement (z)
• Player one, the older brother, has a surplus of z
• Player two, the younger brother, has a surplus of 1 – z
• Nash’s solution is for them to “split†the gains from trade, i.e., {½, ½} is the axiomatic
solution.
• But, now the older brother receives a $0.50 bonus for “sharing nicely,†and the
total gain rises from $1.00 to $1.50
• The Nash bargaining outcome is for the brothers to split to total gains – each receiving
$0.75, meaning the older brother effectively shares half of his bonus.
• By increasing the first player’s gain to reaching agreement, he becomes more eager to reach
agreement, and “shares†his gain with his brother.
15
Bonuses for agreement
• Giving a bonus for reaching agreement is similar to incentive
compensation schemes used by many companies.
• When salespeople are offered bonuses it increases their eagerness to
reach agreement and this induces them to accept “weakerâ€Â
agreements.
• So giving salespeople such a bonus driven incentive will lead to lower prices
when they negotiate with customers.
• (This concept will be further addressed in chapter 20)
16
Alternatives to agreement
• Nash’s bargaining solution incorporates the effect of alternatives to
agreement on the agreement itself. This creates some sound
bargaining advice:
• To improve your own bargaining position, increase your opponent’s gain
from reaching agreement, S2(z) – D2, or reduce your own gain from reaching
agreement, S1(z) – D1.
• When you increase your opponent’s gain in agreement, you make him more
willing to agree.
• Reducing your own gain makes you less willing to compromise and helps to
improve your position.
17
How Nash’s view differs from strategic
• The strategic view of bargaining places a greater emphasis on timing
and commitment in determining the outcome of the game.
• With the labor/management example, the union’s commitment to strike,
or management making the first move, changes the equilibrium of the
game.
• But neither action changes the gains of the agreement so neither would
affect the Nash bargaining outcome.
• The Nash bargaining outcome incorporates the idea that if you
decrease your own gain to agreement you become a better
bargainer.
• EXAMPLE: the best time to ask for a raise is when you have another
attractive offer waiting for you, you have less to gain by reaching
agreement. Your bargaining position improves.
• This is similar to the idea of “opportunity cost.†The opportunity cost of
staying at your current job is giving up the new offer; if the new job pays
more, you’re costs (bottom line) go up.
18
Improving a Bargaining Position
• Discussion Question: When is the best time to buy a car?
• Hint: Remember, car salesmen are generally paid a commission for the sales
they make.
• Discussion Question: How can mergers or acquisitions improve
bargaining power?
19
Merger bargaining example
• A Managed Care Organization (MCO) markets its network to
an employer
• Network value is $100 if it contains either one of two local hospitals
• But the value rises to $120 if it contains both
• And there is no value without at least one of the hospitals
• The gain to the MCO from adding either of the hospitals to
its network when it already has the other is $20
• Nash bargaining solution predicts this is evenly split
• So, each hospital gets $10 for joining the MCO
• But if the hospitals merge and bargain together,
• The MCO can no longer drop one of the hospitals, so the gain from striking a
bargain with the merged hospital is the full $120
• The gain is evenly split in the Nash bargaining solution
• The merged hospitals thus receive $60, a post-merger gain of $40
20
Health care mergers
• In Rhode Island in 2003, Blue Cross Blue Shield (BCBS, the health
insurance company covering state employees) hired PharmaCare to
provide pharmaceutical services.
• PharmaCare created a network of retail pharmacies willing to sell drugs
to state employees at discounted rates.
• The previous contract had allowed employees to buy from any pharmacy but
was considerably more expensive.
• In the new PharmaCare contract, 4 retail pharmacies were excluded from the
plan. These 4 firms lobbied RI legislature to include them in the new plan and
offered to provide the same discounted price but PharmCare declined their
request to join.
• Pharmacare maintained that allowing the other stores to join would
eliminate the savings generated by having a restricted network.
PharmaCare’s bargaining position would deteriorate.
• Many politicians, though, like “freedom-of-choice†bills that would open any
pharmacy willing to meet the negotiated prices.
21
Title?
• Under the 2002 CHAOS (Create Havoc Around Our System) plan, flight
attendants threatened to either stage a mass walkout for several days
or to strike individual flights of Midwest Express, with no advance
warning to either customers or management.
• Midwest Express reacted by cancelling all flight attendant vacation,
and threatened to lock out any employee who participated in the
strike
• Flight attendant union promised funding from its strike fund to
support any attendant who ended up locked out.
• The biggest strength of the union’s threat was that it could be
effective without full implementation.
• The threat of random strikes was enough to push passengers to other
airlines.
• After 30 days of CHAOS, the union successfully negotiated a new
contract.
22
Purchase answer to see full
attachment